Daily Bulletin

The Times Real Estate

.

  • Written by Beth Webster, Director, Centre for Transformative Innovation, Swinburne University of Technology

The recently released Productivity Commission (PC) Trade & Assistance Review is a competent and thorough estimate of the costs of industry assistance. But missing, as always, are estimates of their benefits.

To be fair, the report leaves open the possibility that programs do have benefits. But the subtext is very much that assistance is a cost.

Text book theories fail scrutiny

Industry assistance to businesses is a difficult terrain. Most graduates who have studied a modicum of economics have been schooled in the textbook prediction that giving an advantage to one business, by say preferential purchasing or subsidies, will encourage it to become lazy and inefficient. A short step before joining the gravy train demanding ongoing deals and preferences.

The argument is that if your business has credible long-term prospects, then the finance sector will see this and be willing to invest in your business. Therefore, you do not need subsidies or preference deals from the Australian tax payer. At best, Australians are paying above world price; at worst it is industry welfare.

The bottom line from these economic theories is that rational businesses left to their own devices in a competitive market will produce the best and most efficient of economic outcomes. However, as more data about businesses and markets becomes available, it is becoming apparent that this free-market route has not been taken by some of the most successful economic zones in the world.

Successful overseas industrial models

The Swedish model has been based on long-term collaboration between public agencies and major firms; the Japanese model has relied on technology procurement within state-led public–private networks; and the US model has been partly built on defence-led technology procurement programmes.

Sticky intellectual property policies have been mooted as a significant factor in encouraging multinationals to set up R&D facilities in Israel. Some of the current Australian industry assistance mimics these overseas programs – embedding skills training, technology demonstration and commercialisation.

Overseas there is a considerable amount of case studies and econometric analyses on these programs and policies. Not so here. Australia is still living the dream of the 1970s economic textbooks. We do not regularly evaluate our assistance programs in the standard scientific way. They are not taken seriously by central government agencies.

Why are these 1970s models so appealing?

To be sure, not all industrial programs and policies do improve business productivity. But at present we really do not know which one’s work because we have not put most programs to the empirical test.

The deductive textbook models have considerable appeal. They illustrate – very neatly – how regulations and barriers to competition will lead to overly high prices and monopoly profits.

To present the essential argument in a crisp way, they assume away uncertainty and ignore the role of know-how, reputation, connections and tacit knowledge in business performance. This is quite acceptable for a model of price behaviour.

However, the mistake economists made in the 1970s, (and some apparently still do today), is thinking that a model of pricing can be also used to explain investment (and its twin innovation) or the process of winning customers and sales.

Economic theory struggles to explain firm-level investment

Economic theory struggles to explain firm-level investment. Either it is ad hoc (such as game theory) or relates only to the macro-economy.

Many theories assume investment comprises only physical inputs such as plant and equipment, despite the wide-spread acknowledgement that intangible assets such as computerised information, innovative property (including R&D) and economic competencies (including firm-specific human capital and organisational capital) are about one third of all business assets).

We discover what works before we know why it works

Whereas economic theory has hit an impasse, applied economics and management science have charged forward. As is often the case in new technologies, we discover what works before we know why it works.

Overseas evidence is quite compelling and consistent: networks, clusters and collaborations matter. What we need is domestic evidence, and, more nuanced evidence on what Australian programs work; which ones should be extended or improved and which ones should be scrapped.

Authors: Beth Webster, Director, Centre for Transformative Innovation, Swinburne University of Technology

Read more http://theconversation.com/report-on-industry-assistance-needs-to-go-beyond-just-reporting-costs-63251

Business News

How to Estimate the Right Skip Bin Size for Your Renovation Project

One of the most challenging aspects of planning a renovation project is estimating the amount of waste you'll generate. Choosing a skip bin that's too small means paying for additional bins or picku...

Daily Bulletin - avatar Daily Bulletin

Cool Room Hire: The Ultimate Solution for Temperature-Sensitive Storage

Businesses in the food, pharmaceutical, and event industries often require reliable refrigeration to keep products fresh and safe. Cool room hire provides a flexible and cost-effective solution for ...

Daily Bulletin - avatar Daily Bulletin

Thryv Australia named global winner of the 2025 Microsoft Advertising Partner Awards

Melbourne – 11 March 2025:   Thryv® (NASDAQ: THRY), provider of the leading small business marketing and sales software platform, has been named the global winner of the Microsoft Advertising Part...

Daily Bulletin - avatar Daily Bulletin

LayBy Deals