Daily Bulletin

  • Written by The Conversation Contributor

In the words of Jimmy Porter in Look Back in Anger, “the injustice of it is almost perfect”.

Last week, Jason Potts argued here that the cuts made to around 60 cultural organisations under the Australia Council’s four-year grant program were warranted as, “public funding of the arts should always be temporary”. This contention is not new – it can be found in the 1976 Industries Assistance Commission’s Inquiry into the Performing Arts – and it is not persuasive. As his position may be said to reflect a central current in the neo-liberal critique of cultural subsidy, it is worth examining in detail.

image Mitch Fifield. Mick Tsikas/AAP

Partly, the problem is a matter of language. The remorseless econometricizing of neo-liberalism – “distributional consequences”, “costs of capture”, “effective long term strategic planning” – disguises the way the arts sector actually operates in a modern nation like Australia, and fudges the responsibility artists and the government have for maintaining it.

For in no way do the recent cuts represent a principled response to long-considered policy problems. Arts minister Fifield’s statement that “it was always intended that slightly fewer companies would be funded at a higher level” is an opportunistic reference to a process of review that started in 2006 with Make It New? - a process in which his government has shown precisely zero interest.

I will sketch this history, which is important to know when looking at the cuts and ask the only question that matters: do they make sense? Not “can they be justified by reference to an abstract economic principle?”, but “are they the right ones?”

There is no dispute the Council can cut subsidies to these arts organisations. But should it? What evidence exists that they are beneficial? This is the ultimate aim of cultural policy: to improve future outcomes.

The limits of the economic analysis

image This is not about handouts. David Ip, CC BY-NC-SA

Firstly, let’s not split the difference between “grants” and “investment”, as Potts does, and throw the “hand out” shadow over discussion. It is clear enough that arts and culture are an important source of wealth for Australia, and will only become more so. The “hand out” shadow is not helpful.

His main objection, however, is to the notion of artists’ “expectation of perpetual funding”, which paints all pushback against the cuts as the neglect of basic economic principle.

Is there really an expectation of endless support among the small to medium organisations the Council cut from its client base? If there is (which I doubt) it is much less than among the major organisations it did not defund.

There, the expectation continues. And why wouldn’t it? Why should defence, health and education be “permanent wards of the state” (another Pottsian rhetorical flourish) and not culture?

Neo-liberalism is a limited view of existence that reduces complex forms of behaviour to simplistic and contestable assumptions. One of these is that culture is a private good with little public value.

Try applying this approach to related areas. Why shouldn’t academic research, for example, be restricted in this way? Why shouldn’t failure with an ARC submission incur a penalty, and money to researchers be capped to “incentivize organisations only to put their very best work forward”?

Because it wouldn’t work and it would be wrong. There are many factors in applying for an ARC grant (yes, they are grants too) - but mainly, we don’t think of research as something to be manipulated in this way. Good research is publicly valuable. Researchers are a means of achieving good research. Each submission should be judged on its merits. Only with significant evidence can we say that an individual researcher’s next application is likely to be unworthy.

Of course the crux of this issue is having an effective evaluative mechanism. Choices in cultural policy often involve incommensurable organisations and activities (journals vs. dance companies, community projects vs. research and development). They also involve assessment of contrasting qualities.

An established organization will have a track record, a new one won’t. Decisions are between “achievement” and “potential”. This is not a problem of “asymmetric information” but of assessing different kinds of creative worth. The task is arduous and fraught with error – one reason large cuts to the Council’s client base should prompt our wariness.

In achieving optimal outcomes Potts puts forward a “pump priming” view of cultural subsidy, arguing the government is “much better suited to a temporary seed funding approach”. This was one adopted by the Australian Elizabethan Theatre Trust, the predecessor to the Australia Council, in the 1950s and 1960s. Its history of meddle and muddle does not bear his claim out. Nor am I aware of any international research that lends credence to it.

The claim that “on-going patronage is more suited to corporate or private funding, where building a close relationship… invites mutual monitoring and reduces transaction costs” is similarly bogus.

To mention only the most obvious objection: state support for culture, which in Australia adopts the so-called “patron model”, is mediated by an arm’s length, independent arts agency that attempts to balance creative ambitions, audience wants, and government priorities.

Corporate support is not scrutinised this way, and arises in a commercial context that makes it quite possible that private need will be put before public interest.

The need for a historical analysis

Art is not a widget. Artists and cultural organisations are not abstract factors in a benefit algorithm, endlessly substitutable one for the other. There are limits to their replaceability, comparability, and marketization.

A long-standing problem in cultural subsidy has been finding the right balance of support between new and established artists. This concern can be found as far back as the early 1980s, in Australia Council annual reports.

The numbers of grant submissions had jumped significantly, creating two problems. First, there were more artists to cater for at a time when the Council’s annual allocation was falling in real terms. Second, many projects were small-scale, demanding pernickety decisions from peer reviewers.

During the 1980s various solutions to this problem were attempted. In 1982-3 the Rotherwood Plan tried to specify the type and number of companies to be supported in each major capital. In 1984-5 so-called ceiling funding capped annual federal allocations to organisations at A$300,000. Neither strategy worked.

Then in 1986 the House of Representatives’ Patronage, Power and the Muse (the McLeay Report) made the fateful recommendation to establish a major organisations unit and within a few years the Performing Arts Board, as it was then, lost 80% of its disbursable funds.

This decision has been the chief structural determinant of the distribution of cultural subsidy over the last 25 years. It effectively created a two-tier system: major organisations on the one hand, smaller organisations and independent artists on the other. Through inadvertence or low cunning, governments have often played off one group against the other. The present cuts are a classic example because they only affect the small to medium sector.

image roujo In the 1990s and the 2000s the problem of how to free up money for new artists was eclipsed by a focus on systemic factors in the Nugent Report and the many art form-based inquiries collectively known as “the review cycle”. In 2006 came Make It New? By this stage, arts practitioners were beginning to twig that the problem of absolute level of support was being confounded with questions of redistribution, and rechristened it Make it Cheap. What was needed was a proper industry strategy. So the federal government undertook a period of consultation. There were surveys, committees, focus groups. In 2012 came a report on the Australia Council’s operation, the Trainor Review. It recommended changes to the Council’s peer review structure and (more dubiously) a closer relationship with the federal Minister. It did not recommend, but it very strongly implied, that the money allocated to the major organisations should be opened up to applications from smaller companies (see especially Recommendation 7, “the opening up of the MPA Framework to allow for competitive funding based on peer review”). This is the heart of the funding issue in the post-McLeay period – the ring fencing of the majors. I made a written submission in respect of the Trainor Review. At the time my concern was that the sector avoid another ugly stoush over redistribution. Absolute level of Council support is the vital question. It is possible and desirable for a modern nation to properly fund both large and small cultural organisations. Finally, in 2013 came Creative Australia, a document of breadth rather than depth, which boxed the cultural sector’s problems in one acronym-heavy 151-page document. At least it had some case studies in it. For the first time one could read about the cultural activities a cultural policy was wanting to manage. There the trail of breadcrumbs ends. With the accession of the Liberal party to power in late 2013, Creative Australia went into the bin. It was not replaced by a substantial alternate vision. A mix of whim, resentment and inertia has characterised two and half years of aimless mucking about. The reforms to the Council weren’t undermined entirely. But they were severely curtailed. There is little evidence that the long-term problems with cultural subsidy I have outlined here have been addressed, or even understood. The present cuts are not an expression of a thoughtful approach to the cultural sector. They are a harried attempt to make less money go further in the wake of an unjustifiable reduction to the Council’s annual allocation, and a deliberate weakening of its authority, independence, and effectiveness. No, small cultural organisations should not expect perpetual government support. In that I agree with Potts. But over the last half century, Australia has developed a complex cultural ecology whose inter-dependencies and cooperative relationships do not fit well a model of pure market competition. This ecology took a long time to establish, and sustaining it requires finesse. Remember, this is our national culture we are talking about here, something close to our hearts. In managing the cultural ecology, which is the main job of cultural policy, a number of tools are available, and subsidy is only one. Last year, cultural strategist Cathy Hunt wrote about the potential of no-interest and low-interest loans. In 2014, Leigh Tabrett, one-time head of Arts Queensland, discussed capacity building for small arts organisations. There are alternatives to cheques in the mail, and it is in the interest of the arts sector, not just taxpayers, that they are seriously considered. But tweaking the “funding mix”, as it is sometimes called, relies on a relationship with the federal ministry that is trustworthy, measured, and meaningful. In its first term of office the government has not shown these qualities. There is no reason to ascribe the recent cuts to anything other than on-going bumbling. In a piece this January, Justin Macdonnell, arts manager, author, and wise elder of the cultural sector, a man with no axe to grind and an unparalleled grasp of cultural policy’s complexities, wrote: The more I think about it … the big mistake we have made in public arts policy is to apply linear assumptions and managerial language … to a turbulent domain… In building a world of goals, strategies and KPIs with an almost pathological reliance on the “vision thing”, we have sought to make orderly that which is innately paradoxical. Above all, we have assumed a constant viewpoint to examine and report on this, rather than adopting a multiplicity of long distances and close-ups necessary if any worthwhile understanding [is] to [be] reached. Yes. That’s it. Yes.

Authors: The Conversation Contributor

Read more http://theconversation.com/no-is-a-one-word-poem-59878

Business News

A Guide to Finance Automation Software

When running a business, it is critical to streamline certain processes to maintain efficiency. Too much to spent manually on tasks can wind up being detrimental to the overall health of the organis...

Daily Bulletin - avatar Daily Bulletin

Top Tips for Cost-effective Storefront Signage

The retail industry is highly competitive and if you are in the process of setting up a retail store, you have come to the right place, as we offer a few tips to help you create a stunning storefront...

Daily Bulletin - avatar Daily Bulletin

How Freight Forwarding Simplifies Global Trade Operations

Global trade operations are becoming increasingly complex due to international regulations, customs procedures, and the sheer scale of global logistics. For businesses looking to expand internation...

Daily Bulletin - avatar Daily Bulletin